This is “Export Taxes: Large Country Price Effects”, section 7.22 from the book Policy and Theory of International Economics (v. 1.0). For details on it (including licensing), click here.

For more information on the source of this book, or why it is available for free, please see the project's home page. You can browse or download additional books there. To download a .zip file containing this book to use offline, simply click here.

Has this book helped you? Consider passing it on:
Creative Commons supports free culture from music to education. Their licenses helped make this book available to you.
DonorsChoose.org helps people like you help teachers fund their classroom projects, from art supplies to books to calculators.

7.22 Export Taxes: Large Country Price Effects

Learning Objectives

  1. Identify the effects of an export tax on prices in both countries and the quantity traded in the case of a large country.
  2. Know the equilibrium conditions that must prevail in an export tax equilibrium.

Suppose the United States, the exporting country in free trade, imposes a specific export tax on exports of wheat. A tax on exports will reduce the flow of wheat across the border. It will now cost more to move the product from the United States into Mexico.

As a result, the supply of wheat to the Mexican market will fall, inducing an increase in the price of wheat. Since the United States is assumed to be a large country, the price of all wheat sold in Mexico, both Mexican wheat and U.S. imports, will rise in price. The higher price will reduce Mexico’s import demand.

The reduced wheat supply to Mexico will shift supply back to the U.S. market and induce a reduction in the U.S. price. The lower price will reduce U.S. export supply.

These price effects are identical in direction to the price effects of a tariff, an import quota, and a voluntary export restraint.

A new tax-ridden equilibrium will be reached when the following two conditions are satisfied:

PTMex=PTUS+ T

and

XSUS(PTUS)=MDMex(PTMex),

where T is the export tax, PTMex is the price in Mexico after the tax, and PTUS is the price in the United States after the tax.

The first condition represents a price wedge between the final U.S. price and the Mexican price equal to the amount of the export tax. The prices must differ from the tax because U.S. suppliers of wheat must receive the same price for their product regardless of whether the product is sold in the United States or Mexico, and all wheat sold in Mexico must be sold at the same price. Since a tax is collected at the border, the only way for these price equalities within countries to arise is if the price differs across countries by the amount of the tax.

The second condition states that the amount the United States wants to export at its new lower price must be equal to the amount Mexico wants to import at its new higher price. This condition guarantees that world supply of wheat equals world demand for wheat.

The export tax equilibrium is depicted graphically in Figure 7.37 "Depicting an Export Tax Equilibrium: Large Country Case". The Mexican price of wheat rises from PFT to PTMex, which reduces its import demand from QFT to QT. The U.S. price of wheat falls from PFT to PTUS, which reduces its export supply also from QFT to QT. The difference in the prices between the two markets is equal to the export tax rate T.

Figure 7.37 Depicting an Export Tax Equilibrium: Large Country Case

Notice that there is a unique set of prices that satisfies the equilibrium conditions for every potential export tax that is set. If the tax was set higher than T, the price wedge would rise, causing a further increase in the Mexican price, a further decrease in the U.S. price, and a further reduction in the quantity traded.

Key Takeaways

  • An export tax will lower the domestic price and, in the case of a large country, raise the foreign price.
  • An export tax will decrease the quantity of exports.
  • The export tax will drive a price wedge, equal to the tax rate, between the domestic price and the foreign price of the product.
  • With the export tax in place in a two-country model, export supply at the lower domestic price will equal import demand at the higher foreign price.

Exercise

  1. Jeopardy Questions. As in the popular television game show, you are given an answer to a question and you must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is “a tax on imports,” then the correct question is “What is a tariff?”

    1. The kind of power a country is said to have when its exports make up a significant share of the world market.
    2. The direction of change of the domestic price after an export tax is implemented by a domestic country.
    3. The direction of change of the foreign price after an export tax is implemented by a large domestic country.
    4. The price of tea in the exporting country if the exporter sets an export tax of $0.75 per pound and if the importer country price is $4.75 inclusive of the tax.
    5. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, this is the effect on exports of wheat if an export tax on wheat is implemented.
    6. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, this is the effect on foreign imports of wheat if an export tax on wheat is implemented by an exporting country.