This is “Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs): Large Country Price Effects”, section 7.19 from the book Policy and Theory of International Economics (v. 1.0). For details on it (including licensing), click here.

For more information on the source of this book, or why it is available for free, please see the project's home page. You can browse or download additional books there. To download a .zip file containing this book to use offline, simply click here.

Has this book helped you? Consider passing it on:
Creative Commons supports free culture from music to education. Their licenses helped make this book available to you.
DonorsChoose.org helps people like you help teachers fund their classroom projects, from art supplies to books to calculators.

7.19 Voluntary Export Restraints (VERs): Large Country Price Effects

Learning Objectives

  1. Identify the effects of a voluntary export restraint, or export quota, on prices in both countries and the quantity traded.
  2. Know the equilibrium conditions that must prevail in a voluntary export restraint (VER) equilibrium.

Suppose the United States, an exporting country in free trade, imposes a binding export quota, often called a voluntary export restraint (VER) when implemented bilaterally, on wheat exports to Mexico. The VER will restrict the flow of wheat across the border. Since the United States is a large exporter, the supply of wheat to the Mexican market will fall, and if the price remained the same it would cause excess demand for wheat in the market. The excess demand will induce an increase in the price of wheat. Since wheat is homogeneous and the market is perfectly competitive, the price of all wheat sold in Mexico, both Mexican wheat and U.S. imports, will rise in price. The higher price will, in turn, reduce demand and increase domestic supply, causing a reduction in Mexico’s import demand.

The restricted wheat supply to Mexico will shift supply back to the U.S. market, causing excess supply in the U.S. market at the original price and a reduction in the U.S. price. The lower price will, in turn, reduce U.S. supply, raise U.S. demand, and cause a reduction in U.S. export supply.

These price effects are identical in direction to the price effects of an import tax and an import quota by the importer country, and an export tax by the exporting country.

A new VER equilibrium will be reached when the following two conditions are satisfied:

MDMex(PVMex)=Q¯

and

XSUS(PVUS)=Q¯,

where Q¯ is the quantity at which the VER is set, PVMex is the price in Mexico after the VER, and PVUS is the price in the United States after the VER.

The first condition says that the price must change in Mexico such that import demand falls to the VER level Q¯. In order for this to occur, the price in Mexico rises. The second condition says that the price must change in the United States such that export supply falls to the VER level Q¯. In order for this to occur, the price in the United States falls.

The VER equilibrium is depicted graphically in Figure 7.35 "Depicting a VER Equilibrium: Large Country Case". The Mexican price of wheat rises from PFT to PVMex, which is sufficient to reduce its import demand from QFT to Q¯. The U.S. price of wheat falls from PFT to PVUS, which is sufficient to reduce its export supply also from QFT to Q¯.

Figure 7.35 Depicting a VER Equilibrium: Large Country Case

Notice that a unique set of prices satisfies the equilibrium conditions for every potential VER that is set. If the VER were set lower than Q¯, the price wedge would rise, causing a further increase in the Mexican price and a further decrease in the U.S. price.

At the extreme, if the VER were set equal to zero, then the prices in each country would revert to their autarky levels. In this case, the VER would prohibit trade. This situation is similar to an export embargo.

Key Takeaways

  • A VER implemented by an exporting country will reduce the domestic price and, in the case of a large country, raise the foreign price.
  • The difference between the domestic and foreign price after the VER represents a quota rent.
  • A VER will reduce the quantity of exports to the quota amount.

Exercise

  1. Jeopardy Questions. As in the popular television game show, you are given an answer to a question and you must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is “a tax on imports,” then the correct question is “What is a tariff?”

    1. The direction of change of the domestic price after a binding VER is implemented by an exporting country.
    2. The direction of change of the foreign importer price after a binding VER is implemented by a large exporting country.
    3. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, this is the effect on the domestic price after a nonbinding export quota is implemented by an exporting country.
    4. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, this is the effect on the quantity of wheat exports if a binding VER is implemented.
    5. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, this is the effect on foreign imports of shoes if a binding VER is implemented by an exporting country.